Loading...

Consumption patterns and lifeworlds: using the example of convenience food

©2014 Textbook 67 Pages

Summary

This paper offers remarkable insights into the German food market and its consumers. A solid theoretical foundation is laid by classical as well as modern authors. The works of these authors form the basis for the theoretical analysis on a social determination of taste. In the following, the field of sociology of consumption is taken into account and analysed.<br>In the practical part, consumers are researched using lifeworlds as a tool of categorization of German households. In the market research economy, lifeworlds are widely perceived as an appropriate tool for researching present and future market developments. The analysed empirical data on purchasing behaviour was provided by the market research study Typology of Desires 2010. Results in the direction of a social determination of taste offer valuable perceptions for theorists and practitioners alike.

Excerpt

Table Of Contents



5
Introduction
If someone ever stayed in the supermarket catching a glimpse in the other persons' shopping
baskets, questions such as "Why does this person buy these things?" or "What is the reason that
I consume different aliments than the other does?" may have arisen. In the framework of this
paper it will be shed light on a question whose response does not have solely impact on
sociology of consumption but also on topics different from sociology regarding the coherence of
social origin and consumption behaviour.
In the first part, I spread out the relation of sociology and consumption. At first in a literal
understanding and at next its development as a subfield of sociology. The second part
constitutes the basis for deeper empirical analysis. Foundations are laid by Bourdieu and Ritzer
and the conception of lifeworld. Lifeworld forms the basis from which further deeper empirical
analysis is started from. In the last part, I conduct analysis of consumption behaviour with the
help of descriptive statistics, contingency tables, and odds ratios to arrive at a deeper insight on
the market of convenience food and its consumers.

6
Part I: Consumption and Sociology
The first part of this work consists of a definition of the field of the study. A closer look is laid
on the literal signification of consumption and sociology. This forms the frame, within which, in
the next step a short outline of the history of sociology of consumption shall be given. Sociology
of consumption is a subfield of sociology which increasingly gains importance in present market
economies in various fields such as market research, consumer research, and social research.
Definition of the field of study
At the core of the topic of consumption patterns and lifestyles stands the notion of sociology of
consumption. According to Max Weber, sociology is "the science whose object is to interpret
the meaning of social action and thereby [to] give a causal explanation of the way in which the
action proceeds and the effects which it produces. By "action" in this definition is meant the
human behaviour when and to the extent that the agent or agents see it as subjectively
meaningful." (Weber 1991, p.7)
Whereas this definition of sociology apparently focuses on human kind and its actions, the
notion of consumption according to Wiswede (2000, p.24) contains a meaning which focuses on
human action as well, namely that consumption is the purchase and private usage of economic
goods and services. By directly contrasting the meaning of sociology and consumption one is
even more astonished why sociology of consumption by academics is labelled to be quite
underdeveloped as these two notions seem to be predestinated to work together.
So, sociology of consumption can said to be the sub-discipline of sociology aiming at
understanding, interpreting and explaining the purchase and private usage of economic goods
and services.

7
Emergence of sociology of consumption
Among sociologists there is consensus that to sociology of consumption cannot be allocated a
stringent development. Shove and Ward (2002, p.230) argue that the development of the field of
sociology of consumption did not follow a stringent line and name classical authors such as
Weber, Veblen and Simmel. It is as Wiswede (2000, p.26) puts it that this field of study is rather
underdeveloped, fragmented and strongly influenced by social criticism.
Wiswede dates the beginning of this development at the 1950s when above all the work of
Riesman, Denney and Glazer laid the foundation for research in this area. The book of Riesman
The lonely crowd : a study of the changing American character was actually published in 1950
and can be seen as a milestone in the history of social sciences.
The next crucial step, as Wiswede mentions, had been in the 1960s when for the first time the
notion of "consumer research" and the category of "social and cultural determinants of
consumer behaviour" appeared. Whereas in these years the first works had been published that
directly connected sociology and consumption, Wiswede mentions that these had been less
academically and more marketing oriented. (Wiswede 2000, p.26-7)
At next, regarding Wiswede, in the 1970s sociology of consumption experienced an upswing.
In these times, writers had been above all Germans such as Hörnig, Hillmann, Wiswede,
Scheuch and Scherhorn. Nevertheless, he accentuates that these did not have a longstanding
influence on sociology of consumption. (Wiswede 2000, p.27)
Ward and Shove (1998, p.230) name Bourdieu and his elaboration on the cohesion of position in
society and lifestyle as one landmark in the young history of consumption sociology. These
authors further argue that since this sub discipline of sociology was not considered as an
autonomous field, analysis of consumption accidentally emerged in the context of sociology. It
was rather seen as a by-product and did not stand in the focus of interest. At this point Shove
and Ward (1998) mention Castells and his work The Urban Question: a marxist approach. In
this book Castells analysed collective consumption and the role of the state. Further numerous
publications emerged in the direction of consumer culture, as for instance Lury, C., 1996.
Consumer Culture. Cambridge: Polity Press. and Slater, D., 1997. Consumer Culture and
Modernity. Cambridge: Polity Press.
In the 1980s and 1990s, Wiswede (2000) identifies a significant upturn of topics in the realm of
sociology of consumption in connection with lifestyle research. Lifestyle research can be

8
associated with sociology of consumption as by many sociologists diverse lifestyles are defined
via consumption styles. (ibid.)

9
Part II: Why do we eat what we eat?
Having laid the foundation, in this section mainstays are put in order to have a solid and stable
basis from which empirical analysis can be made. Bourdieu (1984) serves as the guide for the
methodological direction of investigation. Ritzer (1993) offers the appropriate view for
understanding actual processes in society and the selection of the object of interest. Finally,
lifeworld stands for the conceptual background for the later approach for practical research.
Principal questions that are seen as threads during this elaboration are concerning determinants
of our purchase of nutrition. What are the factors behind our daily food consumption? Why do
we eat what we eat? How is taste constructed? From a sociological perspective, what are the
reasons behind daily purchasing behaviour?
The Social Construction of Taste
The question if taste is learnt independently of the social class of origin, or whether the
adherence to the higher or lower class determines taste and life-style, had been one guiding
question in Pierre Bourdieu's analysis of the French society in the 1960s and in later years. In
1963 and 1967-68 Bourdieu conducted a survey on 1217 individuals. Bourdieu's questionnaires
and analysis aimed at revealing consumption patterns of French households, i.e. "...to determine
how the cultivated disposition and cultural competence..., vary according to the category of
agents and the area to which they applied..." (Bourdieu, 1984, p.13). At the beginning of the
formation of taste, there is socialization. In order to know whether for example a child does not
like to go to the theatre because his or her parents do not like to go, or whether a child's habits
are developed independently of its parents' preferences, one needs to take a closer look at the
process of socialization. With regard to Elkin (1960) socialization is "...the process by which
someone learns the ways of a given society or social group so that he can function within it"
(Elkin, 1960, p.4). During the process of socialization, Elkin (1960) further argues, behavioural
patterns, values and feelings are learnt and internalized. From the example given above, the
child learns the stance to take towards a visit of a theatre.
Which holds for a visit of a theatre can be broadened to nearly every good and practice. Between
the final consumption of a good/service and socialization, Bourdieu (1986) inserts the concept
of habitus. Whereas, socialization is determined by the social environment the individual lives

10
in, habitus, among other things, is determined by socialization. More explicitly, habitus shall be
seen as a kind of transmitter between the capacities to practice, to produce, to work and the
capacity of taste, to the ability to make judgements of other individuals' practices, one's own
actions and, according to Bourdieu (1984, p.170), to employ a "...system of classification of
these practices." The before mentioned capacities can be said to equate general acting. This
acting defines and determines the habitus and is primarily conditioned by socialization. The
latter judgements on practices and system of classification can be seen as products of habitus.
This kind of organizing the environment results in behaviour and is finally expressed in life-
style. Habitus is differing from one person to the other, since habitus finally depends on an
individual's conditions of living, of existence, after all on socialization. These translated
conditions of existence into habitus become presented via life-style. But habitus is not just a
means to the end of life-style. It holds that on the one side, habitus structures acting and its
perception, and on the other side, this perception is defined by classification which is an
internalization of class differences. However, a social class, to which a certain habitus adheres,
does not define its values, its tastes, its practices etc., emanating from beliefs or opinions about
their own, solely rooting in socialization. Social classes define themselves, based on impressions
from themselves and on impressions to other classes, so on class differences. A social class is
placed in a social space, and within this space, its position is determined by the intensity of
differences to other classes. These differences are differences arising from habitus of the
different classes. (Bourdieu, 1984, p.
170-2)
Habitus becomes apparent in life-style and is thereafter recognizable by others, defining their
own position. With regard to the obviousness of habitus, Bourdieu (1984, p.173) notes that
habitus creates practical metaphors. He calls it practical metaphor as all individuals belonging to
the same class, possess the same style which makes every person a metaphor of the other.
In other words, all members within a social class are characterized by the same practices and
goods, which makes individuals analog to each other. "Taste, the propensity and capacity to
appropriate (materially or symbolically) a given class of classified, classifying objects or
practices, is the generative formula of life-style..." (Bourdieu, 1984, p.173).
In his book Distinction ­ A Social Critique of the Judgment of Taste, Bourdieu further
distinguishes between the dominant class and the working class, sometimes also called
dominated class. This dualistic distinction is caused by the unequal distribution of economic and

11
cultural capital. Whereas the dominated class in comparison to the dominants is characterized by
having relatively less cultural and economic capital, within the dominant class Bourdieu (1984,
p.173) further differentiates regarding the relative holding of these two forms of capital. Class
fractions, as he calls these subdivisions, are characterized by different asset structures,
signifying the composition of the total amount of capital, in economic capital and cultural
capital. According to Bourdieu (1986, p.47), cultural capital in the context of his works can take
three forms. At first, in the form of the constitution of mind and body. Secondly, in material
form via cultural goods such as pictures, books, etc. Finally also in an institutionalized state,
which implies graduations and educational certificates. Economic capital is much simpler to
grasp. It merely contains everything which is directly convertible to money and could be
institutionalized, as e.g. property rights. (Bourdieu, 1986, p.47)
Not by accident, Bourdieu (1986) denominated the working class as dominated class and the
upper class as dominant. The body as a "...materialization of class taste..." makes this
predominance of the upper class most evident (Bourdieu, 1986, p.190). Bourdieu (1986, p.384)
states that if the dominated class were able to perceive their own body with the eyes and the
values of the dominant class, fundamental principles of class affiliation and class identity were
affected and questioned. The different rapports of the dominant and dominated classes to their
bodies is representative for many other realms in life. The dominated class does not have any
chance of long-term resistance to the imposition of preferences by the dominant class, except in
the case of a formation of loyalty to its being and its position in the social hierarchy. By taking a
look at the goods consumed by the working class, according to Bourdieu (1986, p.386), the
impression arises that the working class tries to copy the dominant class. Bourdieu names
affordable copies of luxury goods as indicators for the phenomena of imitation of the life-style
of the dominants. Actually, the possible reactions of the dominated class towards its position
and its standing in relation to the dominant class, falls into the extremes. Whereas on the one
end, the choice is self-determination, self-confidence, and emancipation from its own standing,
on the other side dominates obedience, compliance and dependence. The actual attitude by the
working class stands in contrast to "...collectively regaining control over social identity"
(Bourdieu, 1986, p.384). From the perspective of the working class, consumption patterns are
strongly influenced and because oriented to the dominant class, indirectly determined by these.
Because of the fact that consumption behaviour finally is the consequence of habitus, and
habitus can be traced back to taste, consumption behaviour is an expression of taste. From

12
Bourdieu's (1986, p.79) stance, the formation of taste takes its beginning with infant learning.
Taste is conditioned by the social class one adheres to. These individuals, which are forming a
social class, by Bourdieu (1986, p.56) are identified to have the same sort of taste. Because all
individuals within a social class share the same sort of taste, taste evolves to an instrument of
distinction and similarity. Hence, taste unites and separates humans. With regard to this
formation of social classes arising from the distinction of taste, Bourdieu (1986, p.466) remarks
that taste functions as a "sense of one's place." It functions as a leader in the social space,
directing to the position in society adjusted. Based on these achievements of taste with regard to
the adherence to social class, finally between middle class and working class different
consumption behaviour of convenience food, as an expression of life-style and taste, may be
observable.
The following part on Weberian rationalities identifies a development in society which Ritzer
labels McDonaldization. Whereas Weber distinguishes between different forms of rationality in
life, Ritzer recognizes these as dominating and critically assesses this development. Based on
the fundamental principles of The McDonaldaization of Society, convenience food is chosen as
the object of research for this work. As a consumer good, it best fits this development of
rationalization in society.
Weberian rationalities
In the Weberian sense there are different types of rationalities: practical rationality, theoretical
rationality, substantive rationality, and formal rationality (Weber, 1968). Each of them has its
distinct characteristics and is applicable to different aspects of life.
-practical rationality-
As the name already indicates, this type of rationality is oriented towards human action. An
action is practically rational if the individual decides strategically what the best mean or action
may be in order to achieve his goal. According to Weber (1958, p.284), modifications of the
practical rational oriented action occur when, on the one hand, means for the attainment change
and, on the other hand, when religious dogmas prevail. Whereas a faithless individual, for
example, may worry and directly engage in the reparation of an act committed, Catholics go to

13
confession, asking for remission. Beliefs in god and the afterlife change considerably rationally
oriented acting. (Weber, 1968, p.551)
-theoretical rationality-
Theoretical rationality principally aims at a rationality through theoretical models and concepts.
It is that all cognitive processes constitute theoretical rationality, or also called intellectual
rationality. At the bottom of this kind of rationality stand philosophers asking metaphysical
questions regarding everyone's being and existence. According to Weber (1968, p.451), this
kind of thinking by the great philosophers of history played a very important role in forming the
ground for theoretical rationality, and hence for critical thinking. (Kalberg, 1980, p.1153-4)
-substantive rationality-
Substantive rationalities are systems organizing everyday life. These systems are closed, i.e.
they do not directly influence other realms of life, and consist of single actions aiming at the
preservation of these systems (Weber, 1968, p.44-45). Because of the fact that these systems are
based on personal opinions and views which guide actions, Kalberg (1980, p.1157) speaks of a
"radical perspectivism". Furthermore because personal preferences and the resulting actions are
consistent with each other, they can be considered as being rational. An example may consider a
family. The opinions a person has with regard to the topic family and its preservation, he or she
guides his/her actions in this direction (Kalberg, 1980, p.1156-7). Substantively rational action
may be the donating of a present to a family member. Substantively irrational action, in modern
times, is clouting of a family member.
-formal rationality-
This type of rationality concerns an organization, or, as Kalberg (1980, p.1159) calls it, a
"structure of domination". These forms of organizations are artificially created and are based on
the presence of legality. Laws, rules and regulations represent the basis for formal rationality
and denote a detachment from times that were characterized by arbitrariness and inequality.
Formal rationality presupposes equality before the law. Forms of organizations in which this
basic principle is applied are not limited to a certain sphere of life, instead they are extending
over economic, legal and scientific domains. A bureaucracy can be identified as the type of

14
organization with the purest form of formal rationality (Weber, 1968, pp.975). (Kalberg, 1980,
p.1159-60)
Processes of rationalization, according to Weber, are generally not following a certain path or
pattern constant through different societies. Instead, because of the fact that a society finds itself
in a continuing interaction with others, rationalization processes are taking place at different
"sociocultural levels" and in different spheres of life. It is even that when a process of
rationalization can be detected in the domain of politics it does not need to be the case that
simultaneously the same development is taking place in economic life, or any other realm of
life. (Kalberg, 1980, p.1150-1) The aim of rationalization is the coping with reality, with the
help of arranging irregularities in society, in systems that award humans with security and
implicitness. This results in the negation of irregularity and arbitrariness, and an affirmation of
regularity and rationality (Weber, 1968, pp.1186). The latter mentioned outcomes of rationality
are these aspects which in Ritzer's (1993) view make up the cornerstone for the
McDonaldization.
McDonaldization
George Ritzer in 1993 further developed and practically applied the aforementioned theory on
rationalization. He identified four notions standing behind the curtain of today's society.
Everyday's events, from going to the supermarket, to eating until watching TV, can be
considered from each of these notions. The sum of the resulting impressions and interpretations
can be labeled as McDonaldization. Efficiency as the first of four aspects mainly stands for less
input for the same or larger amount of output. Calculability implies an appreciation of quantity
relative to quality. The third notion, predictability, considers the fulfilment of expectations via
technology. Replacement of humans and human labor force is the object of interest of the last
notion, control.
-Efficiency-
According to Ritzer (1993, p. 35) efficiency signifies "...the choice of the optimum to a given
end." But because of the fact that optimum shall not be understood literally, but rather as the
nearest possible to optimum, there is always reason for increasing efficiency. Such an increase

15
in efficiency can be reached by certain means. Efficiency also implies the choice of the best
means to a given end. The best means or routines adopted then become institutionalized. Since
these means arise in different social settings in which the human being is set in, means are not
universal but socially conditioned. Here, according to The McDonaldization of Society, a special
role is applied to the fast food restaurant. By the fast food restaurant, this striving for efficiency
is turned into a "near-universal desire". (Ritzer, 1993, p.35)
Ritzer (1993) pronounces the increased efficiency of fast food restaurants compared to cooking
at home or going to a restaurant. Cooking at home presupposes a "trip" to the supermarket,
buying the necessary ingredients, driving home, cooking, etc. These steps are far from being
efficient. At a restaurant, despite the fact that the time waiting for dinner probably takes less
time, persons usually spend more time with eating, talking and drinking. People do not rush
through restaurants and therefore eating at a classic restaurant cannot be considered as efficient.
However, it needs to be admitted that the motivation to go to a restaurant is much different than
being sated most efficiently.
On the other side, fast food restaurants are highly efficient. Routines of employees as well as
customers are advanced and do not contain any losses of time. Parking places are near to the
restaurant and according to Ritzer (1993, p.38), although one has to stand in a line, "food is
quickly ordered, obtained and paid for." The menu does not offer that many choices, and
because food can be eaten with hands it is quickly consumed. A further advance has been
introduced with the drive-through. Through this invention many inefficient steps on the way to
an easy and fast meal had been eliminated. One was not forced to park his car, to walk to the
restaurant and to stand in line, but could remain seated in his car, directly drive to the counter,
pay, receive the food and eat. In other words, the inputs for the output of satiation became
largely reduced and this equals a large increase in efficiency. (Ritzer, 1993, p. 38)
Ritzer (1993, p.35-62) gives multiple examples in order to clarify the predominance of
efficiency, beginning with wireless keyboards and ending with self-service slurpees. He further
considers the invention of kitchen equipment by which efficiency gained access to the field of
cooking. McDonaldized kitchen equipments made cooking far more efficient, as e.g. with the
help of the microwave it became possible to heat meals in one or two minutes which otherwise
would have required a comparatively long time. Convenience food, in the context of the
invention of more efficient kitchen equipment, appears as the appropriate kind of food in order
to increase efficiency as much as possible. Eating at home cannot be more efficient than

16
consuming convenience food, since the input of work compared to the output received cannot be
any higher. In this context, because of the always increasing predominance of efficiency, Ritzer
(1993) holds the opinion that in the near future home cooking will face total extinction. The
salvation of eating at home is the microwave. Although using the microwave implies a
preceding trip to the supermarket, a fully cooked meal
1
is seen by Ritzer as the most efficient
meal at home.
The focus on efficiency as it is brought up by Ritzer, had its most famous precursor in the age of
the industrial revolution, namely through Henry Ford and the assembly line. At an assembly
line, workers stayed directly next to each other and carried out single tasks which represented
one step in a complete process of production. By carrying this out, it became possible to largely
increase production. "...[F]actory could produce 1,000 cars in a day, a level never before seen."
It is not that the mere introduction of the assembly line had led to the leadership in the
automobile industry Ford experienced in these times, but also the idea of vertical integration.
Vertical integration implies that all parts of a car are produced at the same company. (Krebs,
2003, p.16) According to Ritzer (2003, p.59) the invention of the assembly line had a huge
impact on past as well as present times' production processes, since movements to complete
tasks had been strongly reduced. Workers just have to stand still and work, even the task of
carrying the component to the next worker is done by the machine.
-Calculability-
The second pillar of McDonaldization is calculability. Generally speaking, calculability denotes
a development which emphasizes quantity and disregards quality. Ritzer asserts an equalization
of quantity and quality in present societies (Ritzer, 1993, p.62).
With the example of Burger King, Ritzer (1993, p.66) claims that "Hamburgers must be served
within 10 minutes of being cooked. French fries may be allowed to stand under the heat lamp
for no more than 7 minutes. A manager is allowed to throw away 0.3 percent of all food." This
illustrates quite well how much fast food restaurants, and also other entities in society are
accentuating calculability. Factors that appear to be calculable, countable, quantifiable and
generally measurable in numbers are coming to the fore. Ritzer is speaking of the Big Mac as
the symbol to apply the idea of calculability, since, as the name indicates, the customer is
1
Fully cooked meal is one branch of convenience food.

17
expected to assume that he gets a lot for less money (Ritzer, 1993, p.62). One receives large
quantities of food with low quality ingredients.
According to Ritzer, there are numerous examples in daily life which are needed to consider in
order to fully grasp how far actually this predominance of calculability goes. In the realm of
television the vice-president of programming for the TV channel ABC adequately characterized:
"Commercial television programming is designed to attract audiences to the advertisers'
messages which surround the programming... . Inherent creative aesthetic values (that is
quality!) are important, but always secondary." (Ritzer, 1993, p.68) In this context pilots shall be
noticed, which are used in order to measure the attractiveness of further TV productions. The
underlying decisions to continue producing are based on calculable ratings received by
consulting firms.
Although Ritzer explicitly pronounces the effect of the principle of calculability on present
societies, the impact of time and its measuring especially on the production process had been
discovered much earlier. Frederick Taylor had been the real precursor. His so called Time Study
smoothed the ways for considering time as a determining factor in the production process. In the
late 19
th
century, the height of the industrialization in the United States of America, Taylor
measured the time a "first-class man" needed to perform his tasks in a fabric. Based on the
foregone time measurement, Taylor calculated and set the time for completing a certain task in a
production line. The goal of this study was to stop wasting time by the employees and to
increase efficiency. (Ferguson, 1997) Results finally were published in his book "The Principles
of Scientific Management", which is said to be the ancestor of modern management theory.
The concept of calculability stands in tight relation with convenience food. On convenience food
packages there is always written the time for the meal needed to stay in the microwave, oven,
pot, etc. in order to be servable. The customer is able to calculate the time needed for the
preparation of the meal. Exactly this calculability of time makes this type of nutrition so
attractive for the consumer. One can eat whenever one desires to with the advantage that it is not
needed any longer to organize daily routines around mealtimes. Instead, with convenience food
it is made possible to put nutrition in time gaps with the schedule is offering. In the end, this
may lead to the dissolving of classic mealtimes.

Details

Pages
Type of Edition
Erstausgabe
Year
2014
ISBN (eBook)
9783954897476
ISBN (Softcover)
9783954892471
File size
402 KB
Language
English
Publication date
2014 (April)
Keywords
Sociology of consumption Food consumption Consumer research Convenience food Lifeworlds
Previous

Title: Consumption patterns and lifeworlds: using the example of convenience food
book preview page numper 1
book preview page numper 2
book preview page numper 3
book preview page numper 4
book preview page numper 5
book preview page numper 6
book preview page numper 7
book preview page numper 8
book preview page numper 9
book preview page numper 10
book preview page numper 11
book preview page numper 12
book preview page numper 13
67 pages
Cookie-Einstellungen